Readings of the WRM Course

RDV Core Training Program FY98 Activity 2.2

Return to the Content of WRM course


WATER AS AN ECONOMIC GOOD:
THE IDEA AND WHAT IT MEANS IN PRACTICE
L’EAU EN TANT QUE BIEN ECONOMIQUE:
CONCEPTION ET MISE EN PRATIQUE
by
John Briscoe, (1) (2)
 
The World Bank
Washington DC
A paper presented at the World Congress of
the International Commission on Irrigation and Drainage,
Cairo,
September 1996
 
(1) Senior Water Advisor. Email JBriscoe@worldbank.org.  Comments welcome.

(2) This paper does not represent the official views of the World Bank, and should not be represented as such.  The paper represents only the views of the author.


 
ABSTRACT

There is an emerging consensus that effective water resources management includes the management of water as an economic resource. The Dublin Statement of the International Conference on Water and the Environment, for example, states that "water has an economic value in all its competing uses and should be recognized as an economic good". But there is little agreement on what this actually means, either in theory or in practice. This paper provides a simple framework for unbundling the different components of water as an economic resource, provides some data on critical variables, and discusses the policy implications.

The interaction of three critical factors -- -- the value of water, the use cost of water, and the opportunity cost of the resource -- is explored for the cases of urban water supply and irrigation. A review of data on the value of water shows that the value of water used for irrigating foodgrains is very low, typically orders of magnitude less than the value for urban water supply, for environmental purposes and for the irrigation of high-value crops.

The assessment of the relative magnitudes of "use costs" and "opportunity costs" shows that the implications of treating water as an economic resource vary quite widely depending on the sector.

Urban water supply, for example, is a low-volume, high-value use. The "use costs" (incurred in financing and operating the abstraction, transmission, treatment and distribution systems) are relatively high, while the "opportunity costs" (imposed on others as a result of use of the water) are often quite low. Accordingly, the priority issue for the economic management of urban water supplies is usually the commercial operation of the utility.

The situation is quite different for irrigation, which is a high-volume, low-value user of water. The "use cost" of irrigation water is often modest, but when there is competition with urban uses, the opportunity cost is high. While financial sustainability of irrigation systems is important for operation and maintenance reasons, from the point of view of management of water as an economic resource, the key challenge is to ensure that users take the opportunity cost of water into account.

The paper examines data from Spain and the Western United States on the effect of different irrigation management regimes on efficiency and equity within an irrigation district, and shows that it matters a lot how water is managed -- market-like allocation mechanisms are much more efficient and equitable than the more commonly-used alternatives (such as rotation and turn irrigation procedures).

The paper concludes with an examination of how the idea of water as an economic good is incorporated into two well-functioning water resource management models -- the Ruhr/ French river basin management systems, and the Chilean water market system.



 
A NOTE ON UNITS

A bewildering variety of units are used to measure water and its value. This paper mostly uses the units conventional in urban water supply -- US cents per cubic meter. In irrigation (where values are much lower, the usual measure is cents per thousand cubic meters). Much of the literature on the economics of water originates in the United States where the usual measures are cents per thousand gallons (for domestic use) and dollars per acre foot for agricultural use. Useful conversion factors are:

10 US cents per cubic meter = 38 US cents per thousand US gallons

                                            = $100 per thousand cubic meters

                                            = $123 per acre foot



 
1. THE THEORY OF WATER AS AN ECONOMIC GOOD

The idea of "water as an economic good" is simple. Like any other good, water has a value to users, who are willing to pay for it. Like any other good, consumers will use water so long as the benefits from use of an additional cubic meter exceed the costs so incurred. This is illustrated graphically in Figure 1(a), which shows that the optimal consumption is X*. Figure 1(b) shows that if a consumer is charged a price P1, which is different from the marginal cost of supply, then the consumer will not consume X* but X1. The increase in costs (the area under the cost curve) exceeds the increase in benefits (the area under the benefit curve) and there is a corresponding loss of net benefits (called the "deadweight loss".)

Figure 1: Optimal consumption and "deadweight losses" if water is underpriced

 

But what about groups of users, how is welfare maximized for the group (or society) as a whole? The simple logic of Figure 1 applies in the aggregate -- for society as a whole, welfare is maximized when:

 
So far so good, but what actually do we mean by "benefits" and "costs", how are these dealt with in different water-using sectors, and what are the implications? These issues are explored in the next section of this paper.

2. THE VALUE OF WATER

The value of water to a user is the maximum amount the user would be willing to pay for the use of the resource. For normal economic goods which are exchanged between buyers and sellers under a specified set of conditions, this value can be measured by estimating the area under the demand curve. Since markets for water either typically don’t exist or are highly imperfect, it is not simple to determine what this value is for different users of water. A hodgepodge of methods are used to estimate the value of water in different end uses (Gibbons, 1986). These methods include: estimating demand curves and integrating areas under them: examining market-like transactions; estimating production functions and simulating the loss of output which would result from the use of one unit less of water; estimating the costs of providing water if an existing source were not to be available; and asking (with carefully-structured "contingent valuation" questions (Arrow et al., 1993 and Griffin et al, 1995) how much users value the resource.

What is the point of estimating these values, given the crude and inexact nature of the estimates, and given that the value of water varies widely depending on factors such as the use to which it is put, the income and other characteristics of the user, the location at which it is available, season and time, and quality and reliability of the supply?

Most certainly these "ballpark estimates" can never, and should never, be used to make technocratic decisions on allocations and prices (as has sometimes been proposed). But examination of the values which emerge from these estimates do show some striking and remarkably consistent themes which have major implications for policy. To illustrate these themes, it is useful to work with some actual values -- Figure 2 summarizes some data (presented by Moore and Willey, 1991) from the Western United States, where most valuation work has been done. Other compilations (e.g. in Gibbons, 1986) show similar patterns in terms of the relative value of water in different uses.

Conclusions which emerge from Figure 2 (note the log scale on the Y axis) and consistently in similar studies and in meta-studies which draw together large amounts of available data include:


high-value crops (including fruits, vegetables and flowers). The value of water, as reflected in active and sophisticated water markets, is high (typically around 5 US cents per cubic meter.) In public (mostly surface) irrigation systems in the same country, the quality of the irrigation supply is poor, foodgrains are the major crop produced, and the value of water is typically only about 0.5 cents per cubic meter (World Bank, 1994a), orders of magnitude lower than in the private groundwater schemes. Similar very large and persistent differences are found in publicly-run irrigation schemes throughout the developing world. (A comprehensive review of World Bank-financed irrigation schemes (World Bank, 1995) showed that foodgrains were the predominant crop in 90% of such schemes). Before discussing the policy implications of these remarkably consistent findings, it is relevant to summarize a related area of work on the economic value of water, which also has major impacts for policy. There is a substantial literature assessing how users react to changes in the price of water. The concept used is that of "elasticity", with the measure being defined as the % change in use of water for each % increase in the price of water. Once again, there is a striking consistency to the findings (and to their import for resource management, as discussed later). Figure 3 presents some values (again from Gibbons, 1986) which do not purport to be universal, but which illustrate consistent findings in the literature.

In assessing data on elasticity, it is necessary to clear up a confusion generated by a piece of economic jargon. When the price elasticity of demand is less than -1.0 (i.e., when the percentage change in consumption is less than the percentage change in price) then economists say "demand is inelastic with respect to price". The common-sense (but erroneous) interpretation is that demand is not reduced as prices change. In fact, as long as price elasticity is negative, demand is reduced when prices increase.

Figure 3: Range of price elasticities of demand for water in the United States
 

An obvious omission from Figure 3 -- the lack of estimates of the price elasticity of demand in irrigated agriculture -- needs to be explained. This is best done with reference to the place where it has been most studied -- the western United States. In the western US the price elasticity of demand for irrigation water is low. The reason for this low elasticity is not that farmers do not respond to prices (as is often inferred), but rather because users’ reactions to price changes depend on the original price and because irrigation water costs are held artificially low (Gibbons, 1986). In California, for example, where water is priced at $3 per thousand cubic meters, a 10 per cent price increase causes a 5% decline in water use, whereas where water is priced at $14 per thousand cubic meters, a 10 per cent price increase results in a 20% drop in use (Rogers, 1986).

The major point that emerges from the (quite large) literature on the price elasticity of water demand is that, in developing and developed countries alike, the price elasticity is significantly negative, meaning that users react to price increases by reducing demand. A second important point is that the price elasticity is, as common sense would suggest, related to the price level -- the higher the price, the greater the elasticity. (Obvious and common-sensical as these findings may be, they contradict a large body of folk-lore about "non-responsiveness to prices" in the water profession.)

Before concluding this discussion of "value", it is relevant to focus on the issue of the "value" of wastewater treatment, or the "value" of environmental quality. The usual approach to this has been to assume that it is impossible to assess this value and, instead, to promulgate standards (by type of treatment required, quality of effluent stream, or quality of the receiving stream). This is often perceived as a way of "getting round" the issue of value. As was shown in a seminal work by Harold Thomas (1963), setting of a standard is equivalent to imputing a value for the resource. As will be discussed later, there are institutional arrangements for setting standards which violate (at great cost) this understanding, but there are also institutional arrangements which provide practical and proven methods for taking these values into account implicitly in setting standards.


3. THE COST OF WATER

So much for the value side of the equation -- what of the cost side?

In thinking about "the cost of water" it is first necessary to acknowledge that there are two different types of costs incurred in providing water to, say, a household or a field. The first (obvious) cost is that of the constructing and operating the infrastructure necessary for storing, treating and distributing the water. In this paper this is referred to as the "use cost". The second, less obvious, cost is the "opportunity cost" incurred when one user uses water and, therefore, affects the use of the resource by another user. For example, greater abstraction of water by a city might affect the quantity and quality of water available to downstream irrigators, thus imposing costs on these users. (Technically the "opportunity cost" is defined as the value of the water in its highest value alternative use.)

3.1. Use Cost

In discussing "use costs", it is first necessary to define three concepts. First is the concept of "historical costs". Consider the example where a water board constructs a reservoir from which it supplies water to its customers. What should the board charge its customers for the service provided by the reservoir? Frequently, the charging system mimics the mortgage payers of a homeowner -- the Board charges its users that which is necessary to pay for the remaining portion of the debt incurred in financing the dam. This is known as "historical cost" pricing. The second, less intuitively obvious concept is that of "replacement cost pricing". Accountants will argue that the value of the asset (the dam in this case) is not correctly measured by its historic costs (which are often heavily distorted by government intervention), but rather the cost that would be incurred in replacing the asset. The analogy here is that of the housing rental market. If a homeowner has paid off his mortgage he does not charge a tenant nothing -- rather, he charges a rental fee that reflects the replacement cost of the asset. The third concept is that of marginal cost. Economists argue that when someone is thinking about using a bucket of water, they should not be told (through prices) what it costs to produce that water but, rather, be told the cost that will have to be incurred if capacity needs to be expanded to produce another cubic meter of water (Turvey and Warford, 1974). Where cost curves are relatively flat, the distinction between the former (average costs) and the latter (marginal costs) is unimportant. When costs are falling (as happens where there are economies of scale, for instance in treatment plants), marginal costs are less than average costs. For raw water, however, the situation is just the opposite, because the closest, cheapest sources are those which are used first. The cost curve for raw water, then is almost always rising, and marginal costs are greater than average costs.

3.2. Opportunity Cost

It is obvious that measuring of the opportunity cost of water is a difficult task. It needs a systems approach and a number of more or less heroic assumptions about real impacts and responses to these. (To cite one example, a systems model was developed for the Colombia River Basin in the northwestern US, and the opportunity cost of water diverted to irrigation estimated by assessing the losses of revenue to the hydropower operators on the river (Gibbons, 1986).)

What can be said with certainty is that:


4. THE BALANCING OF VALUE AND COSTS

The overall "economic cost of water", therefore, comprises two separate components -- the use cost and the opportunity cost. It is useful to maintain and deepen this disaggregation in thinking about how the idea of "the cost of water" is understood, and how this understanding frames the public, political and theoretical discussions of water management. In doing this, it is instructive to recognize that there are a variety of ways in which the "use cost" and opportunity cost are perceived, and how different institutional arrangements mean that users are faced with different vectors of "use" and "opportunity cost".

In exploring these relationships it is useful to first define the "golden standard", namely that combination of use and opportunity costs which ensure that users take the full economic costs of using water into account. As illustrated in Figure 4 , a user faces the full economic cost when he (a) has to pay a "use cost" which corresponds to the marginal financial cost of supplying the water to him and (b) incurs an opportunity cost which reflects the value of water in its best practical alternative use. This combination of "use cost" and "opportunity cost" is shown in the upper right hand corner of Figure 4 (overleaf).

So much for theory, what about practice? This varies by sector and by country. A few examples will illustrate the general situation.

4.1. Urban water supply in industrialized countries

Practice in urban water supply in industrialized countries deviates from "the economic optimum" in two ways which are significant in theory but of little importance in practice. Regarding "use charges", water utilities in industrialized countries are generally operated on commercial or quasi-commercial principles (World Bank, 1994), and recover the full average financial costs (Level III in Figure 4, overleaf) from users. There are two reasons why few utilities operate at level IV (the economic optimum). First, although there are negative economies of scale for raw water, there are positive economies of scale for the major civil works which account for much of urban water supply costs. Accordingly, marginal costs may not be different from (and may actually be less than) average costs. Second, setting tariffs to cover average costs is a simple, transparent process which mimics that of commonplace financial transactions. A corollary is that the (small) economic benefits of moving to marginal cost pricing have to be weighed against the (large) administrative and governance costs of dealing with a system which "defies common sense" for most customers.

Urban water tariff setting also deviates from the economic optimum in that the opportunity costs of water are often not visible to the utilities (except in well-functioning water resource management systems, two of which are described later in this paper). In any case, these opportunity costs are, from the point of view of urban water supplies, usually very small relative to the financial costs of abstracting, transporting, treating and distributing water. For the urban water sector Figure 4 would usually look like a "tall L", as shown in Figure 5.

The "tall-L" shape for urban water (Figure 5) arises both because the value of raw water for municipal uses is typically (as shown in Figure 2) an order of magnitude higher than the value of the next best use, and because the costs of raw water constitute only a minor part (typically less than 20%) of the cost of water as delivered to the customer. The bottom line, then, is that, although opportunity costs are often not taken into account, the "tall-L" shape of Figure 5, means that, in practice, urban water supply pricing in industrialized countries deviates little from the economic optimum.
 



 
Figure 4: Schematic representation of the definitions of use cost and opportunity cost

Use Cost (Financial Cost)

 Opportunity Cost when:

 Figure 5: The relative magnitudes of use costs and opportunity costs for urban water supply
 



4.2. Urban water supply in developing countries

In developing countries the situation is quite varied and generally quite different from that in industrialized countries. The first difference comes on the cost side. Many cities in developing countries are growing rapidly. In many cities incomes are also increasing and industrial demand is growing. The net result is that the demand for municipal water is often growing very fast and new sources have constantly to be found. A consequence is that the costs of urban supplies from new sources are growing rapidly -- in current World Bank-financed projects the cost of a cubic meter of raw water for a city is typically 2 to 3 times greater (in real terms) than was the case in the last project (World Bank, 1992). In terms of Figure 4, this means that the difference between marginal (level IV) costs and average (level III) costs are typically substantially greater for developing countries than for industrialized countries. Unfortunately the story does not stop there. Urban water supplies in most developing countries have been financed out of general revenues. In many cases these costs are fully subsidized, with the utility responsible only for operation and maintenance costs (level I). In other cases the costs are computed in historical terms, which typically greatly undervalue the assets of the utility. With regard to opportunity costs, the situation is similar to that in industrialized countries -- they are not taken into account, but are also usually small relative to real financial costs. In a typical case in India, for instance, average financial costs ("use costs") are about 50 US cents per cubic meter, whereas the opportunity cost of water (for irrigation of foodgrains) is about 0.5 cents per cubic meter, a difference of two orders of magnitude.

The important challenge for urban water utilities in developing countries, is, therefore (a) to reduce costs by more efficient operation (which increasingly means substantial involvement of the private sector (Serageldin, 1995 and World Bank, 1994)); and (b) to raise tariffs from their very low levels (which typically cover less than one-third of costs (World Bank, 1992)). Worrying about opportunity costs they impose -- the short leg on the L in Figure 5 -- is not a priority problem for urban water utilities in developing countries.

4.3. Privately-financed irrigation

The great distinction here is not between industrialized and developing countries, but rather between publicly- and privately-financed irrigation schemes.

In most countries private irrigators bear the full financial costs of the schemes they construct and thus implicitly face financial costs at level III in Figure 4. In a number of countries this is not the case, with subsidies substantially reducing the financial costs incurred by private irrigators. (Subsidized energy prices for water pumping is widely practiced, from the United States to India. While it has been, or is being, phased out in many countries, in some -- India is a prime example -- farmers benefit from large subsidies for irrigation pumping.)

Private irrigators seldom face any opportunity costs for the water they use. Where groundwater is used, this has led to the unsustainable pumping of aquifers, sometimes on a huge scale, such as the Ogallala aquifer in the United States (Rogers, 1986). Where surface water is used, this is often in the context of a "prior appropriation" water doctrine which implicitly encourages the ignoring of opportunity costs.

4.4 Publicly-financed irrigation

Public irrigation systems throughout the world share several striking characteristics. First, as has been documented in countries as different as the United States (Reissner, 1986, Worster, 1992, Bradley, 1995), and India (Wade, 1986), they have been enormous sources of political patronage. Typically these investments have been subsidized almost completely by the State. In most developing countries charges have been much lower than those required even to pay for operations and maintenance costs (World Bank, 1995). In Bihar in India, for example, water charges are not sufficient to even cover the costs of collection (Rogers, 1992)!

The issue of "recovering the costs of operations and maintenance" has been the focus of much debate in the irrigation community. This is an important debate, first, because the associated issue of ensuring that systems are maintained and provide a good-quality service to farmers is obviously appropriate and central to improving irrigation performance. This issue thus deservedly occupies center-stage in reviews, such as a recent one by the Operations Evaluation Department of the World Bank (1995). An important finding from such reviews is that the supply side of this question is at least as important as the demand side. It has been shown repeatedly that cost recovery in irrigation systems makes little positive difference unless the revenues so collected are applied to improving the quality of service received by the farmers. Where these revenues go to a central treasury (as is frequently the case), there is little improvement in irrigation performance if "costs are recovered".

The "opportunity cost" axis is an important and subtle one in canal irrigation systems (the dominant technology in public irrigation districts). A typical situation is one in which users are charged a small amount (often zero) for the "use cost", but where they do take account of one restricted measure of the opportunity cost of the resource. The best-known example of this is the rotational rationing system of North India (the so-called "waribandi system"). As students of the system have pointed out, in this setting water is often the limiting production resource. Each farmer, therefore, faces an "opportunity cost" which influences the way in which he uses that resource. While this is true (and is often neglected in criticisms of such systems) it should be observed that the opportunity cost varies considerably depending on "alternative uses" which come into play. In the waribandi system the "opportunity cost" is essentially that of the opportunities which the individual farmer foregoes on another (unirrigated) field, assuming he has one. The "opportunity cost" would evidently be greater if all farmers in a particular distributory were included, since it is the value placed by the highest alternative use which defines the opportunity cost. (This is confirmed by the fact that, although not formally sanctioned, limited water markets -- often involving only neighbors -- exist in waribandi-like systems.) Similarly if it were possible (as is increasingly the case) to transfer the water among a wider universe of potential users of that water (which will usually include other farmers, and may include neighboring towns and industries), then the "opportunity cost" would be greater still. While "the best alternative use" needs to take into account location and the hydraulic connections possible between users, it is certain that the restrictive "opportunity cost" implicit in rationing systems (like waribandi) will often represent large underestimates of the true opportunity costs (and will therefore mean that farmers are facing both use and resource costs which represent substantial underestimates of the true costs). Under such circumstances, as explained earlier, deadweight losses are likely to be substantial.

The magnitude of these losses has been estimated in a seminal assessment of different irrigation systems in Spain and the United States. Maass and Anderson (1978) did simulation analyses of the effects of different water allocation procedures on the economic impact of water shortages. In the "turn" system, farms are served in order of location along the canal. When water reaches a farmer, he takes all he needs during the period, before the next farmer is served (a procedure followed in Valencia). In the "rotation" system each farm has a reserved time in which to irrigate in each period, but the water delivered in this time varies on each rotation depending on the flow in the ditch (a procedure followed at the time of the study in Fresno, Utah and Murcia.) In the "market" system, all water users bid each period for the water used to irrigate their crops and the water is allocated to the highest bidders (a procedure followed in Alicante). As shown in Figure 6 below:

 

Figure 6: Relative efficiency of different American and Spanish water management procedures when water to an irrigation district is reduced by 10% (after Maass and Anderson, 1978).

 

A relevant aside is to note the effects of different water management regimes on the distribution of losses amongst farmers when there are shortfalls in water availability. The standard measure for inequality is that of the Gini coefficient -- as shown in Figure 7, the Gini coefficient is:

Figure 7: Measures of equality -- the Gini coefficient


As shown in Figure 8, in both Spain and the United States, the market system was markedly superior to the turn and rotation systems, in terms of the equity of distribution of the losses resulting from a water shortage. As pointed out by the authors, "although it is a doctrine of many welfare economists that procedures that rank high in efficiency will do poorly in distributing income equally among beneficiaries, while procedures that do well in distributive equality will be inefficient.... this conventional wisdom does not apply to a wide variety of conditions in irrigated agriculture" (Maass and Anderson, p 391.)

Figure 8: The equity of different water allocation systems
 



4.5 The implications for irrigation vis a vis urban uses

In summary, when considering the relative magnitudes of the "use cost" and opportunity cost of irrigation, the situation is almost exactly the opposite of that pertaining for urban water supply. Financial costs of irrigation systems are usually much lower (per unit of water) than they are for urban water; and opportunity costs are much higher, both absolutely and relatively, as shown in Figure 9. Ignoring opportunity costs is thus a matter of minor practical importance when it comes to the economic management of urban water supplies, but a matter of huge practical significance when it comes to irrigation. As illustrated schematically in Figure 10, the shape for irrigation is a "flat L" in contrast to the "tall L" (Figure 5) for urban water supply!

Figure 9: Illustrative values of use and opportunity costs for urban supplies and irrigation

 
 



 Figure 10: The relative magnitudes of use costs and opportunity costs for irrigation
 
Finally, it is instructive to return to the graphical format developed in Figure 4 to summarize the issues on use and opportunity costs as they pertain to different water-using sectors. Figures 11 and 12 (overleaf) provide a schematic representation of how the management of different water-using sectors deviate from the economic optimum.
 

Figure 11: Schematic representations of deviation from economic pricing for: urban water supply

 



 Figure 12: Schematic representations of deviation from economic pricing for: irrigation

  

Opportunity Cost

5. WATER AS AN ECONOMIC GOOD --
EXAMPLES OF GOOD PRACTICE

5.1. Where water quality management is the principal challenge --

The Ruhr/French model

Probably the most widely-admired water resource management model is that which was developed in the Ruhr Basin in Germany in the early part of this century, and subsequently adapted on a national scale by France in 1964. The evolution and details of the Ruhr and French experiences have been described elsewhere (Ruhrverband, 1992; Cheret, 1994; Serageldin, 1994). The core elements of this system are:

How does the economic value of water come into play in the Ruhr/French type of system? With regard to "use costs" the answer is simple -- the users pay the full financial cost of the infrastructure required to deliver water to them. The way in which the model deals with opportunity costs is more important and less obvious. Abstraction fees are set through a negotiation process. If there is a shortage of water and a potential user without access wants water (or an existing user wants more water), then that user’s voice will be heard in the parliament in pushing for higher abstraction prices so as to bring supply and demand into balance. In economic terms this "next best use" is precisely what is meant by "opportunity cost"! On the quality dimension (of dominant importance in industrialized countries), the operation of the basin agency is similar -- the costs imposed on others in the basin are revealed in both the work of the technical agency and in the course of negotiations, and pollution fees accordingly set in part to take account of these "externalities".

On the one hand, then, opportunity costs do come into play in decisions on prices. On the other hand, this expression is indirect and muted by a complex administrative process. As a result, the signals on opportunity cost in such a system to not have the desired specificity and flexibility. While administratively-set prices in these systems are affected by opportunity costs, they cannot mimic a market (which, as described in the next section, automatically differentiates by location, quality, season and other complex and changing variables.)

5.2. Where water scarcity is the principal challenge -- experience with water markets

In arid areas of the world the foremost water resources management problem has long been that of allocating scarce water among competing uses and users. (Glick (1969) has described the management of water allocation in detail for medieval Spain.) A wide variety of approaches have been taken, and are taken to this problem.

In the twentieth century the most common approach has been a combination of "first come-first served" (known as the "prior appropriation doctrine" in the Western United States (Worster, 1992)), and the augmentation of supplies through massive investments and allocation of the additional water on political grounds. The problems with such an approach has become manifest throughout the world -- the financial costs are enormous, precious water is wasted on low-value activities, while high-value uses cannot secure adequate supplies, and environmental destruction and degradation are the norm (Worster, 1992, Postel, 1992, and Reissner, 1986). Recently there has been a surge of interest in the use of water markets as a means of performing this allocation function in an efficient and consensual fashion.

Water markets have a long history both informal, as documented by Shah (1993) for groundwater in Western India, and formal, most notably in Spain (Maass and Anderson, 1978) ). There have been major developments in Australia (Dudley, 1994), and innovative proposals on the use of markets to solve international water disputes in the Middle East (Fisher, 1994). Most of the attention, however, has been focused on the Western United States, where a wide range of water markets have developed (Saliba and Bush, 1987), with some sophisticated developments (such as the recent development of electronic water markets for the huge Westlands Water District in the Central Valley of California (Zachary, 1996)).

In the context of the present discussion of the economic management of water, it is instructive to concentrate on a single, much-discussed case, that of the water markets in Chile. The key policy decision in Chile was the separation of land and water rights in 1981 and the simultaneous encouragement of trading of water without restriction.

The water market is a brilliant conceptual solution to the enduring problem of reconciling practical and economic management of water. On the one hand, "common sense pricing" suggests that the water management unit charges users for the "use costs" -- the investment and operating costs incurred in storing and delivering the water to the user. (It is this which is done by users’ associations who operate water systems at various levels in Chile). The problem arises because these financial costs are much lower (often an order of magnitude lower) than the "opportunity cost" (which reflects the value of the best alternative use of the water). (In the Limari Basin, in Chile, for example, the "use cost" is about 0.5 cents per cubic meter, and the opportunity cost about 5 US cents per cubic meter.) The existence of a water market means, however, that behavior is not driven by the financial cost of the water but rather by the opportunity cost -- if the user values the water less than it is valued by the market, then the user will be induced to sell the water. This is the genius of the water market approach -- it ensures that the user will in fact face the appropriate economic incentives, but de-links these incentives from the tariff (which is set on "common-sense" grounds).

In well-regulated river basins in arid areas of Chile, the water markets function as one would wish: within a particular area water is traded from lower-value uses to higher-value uses; prices are responsive to both temporary (seasonal) scarcity as well as longer-term scarcity; trading is quite active. Two comments are appropriate here. First, it is evident that no administrative mechanism (even the very good Ruhr and French systems) can mimic water markets in transmitting information on opportunity costs in such a flexible and specific way. Second, it is important to note that water markets are not a simple panacea. The major challenge facing water resources managers in Chile (see Briscoe, 1996) is more effective basin-level management which will both complement and enhance the workings of the water markets.

From the perspective of the economic management of water , a critical issue is the "breadth" of the water markets, with the dictum being "the less restrictions there are on water trades, the more the true opportunity cost will come into play". In Chile, where water can (and is) traded from agriculture to towns, a farmer who owns water rights faces the full opportunity cost of the resource. In many instances (such as the water market of Alicante, and the large market in the Northeast Colorado Water Conservation District) there are specific, and sometimes absolute, prohibitions on the sale of water to non-agricultural users. In such situations, the opportunity costs are obviously truncated, with important resulting distortions in the economic signals.



 
6. CONCLUSION AND A CAVEAT

This paper attempts to develop a framework for thinking about management of water as an economic resource and to assess the policy implications in light of available empirical evidence.

Three principal conclusions emerge from the discussion. First, economic development and environmental sustainability in many countries depend on considering water as a scarce resource, and using economic principles for its management. Second, the challenge is particularly great with respect to irrigated agriculture which is, simultaneously the largest user of water in many countries and the sector which is managed (in most places) least like an economic resource. Third, while it is clear that the distance between the "bad" bottom left-hand corner of Figure 4 and the "good" top right-hand corner is great (particularly for irrigation), there are also examples of good practice which show that change is possible and how it can be effected.

Finally, it is important to acknowledge that the idea of "water as an economic good" is but one of a triad of related ideas which will increasingly shape the way in which societies are organized (and water managed) in the latter part of the twentieth century. These ideas (explored in more detail elsewhere (Briscoe, 1995)) are:

 
References
Arrow, Kenneth, Robert Solow, Paul Portney, Edward Leamer, Roy Radner and Howard Schuman. 1993 Report of
the NOAA panel on contingent valuation. Department of the Interior, Washington DC.

Bradley, Bill. 1996. Time Present, Time past: A Memoir. Knopf, New York.

Briscoe, John. 1994. Implementing the new water resources policy consensus: Lessons from good and bad practices. in: Putting Agenda 21 into Practice, ed. J.Lundqvist and T. Jonch-Clausen, Linkoping University, Sweden. pp 83-100.

Briscoe, John. 1995. "Implementing the World Bank’s Water Resources Management Policy Paper -- Emerging Challenges", Keynote speech (available in the form of slides) to the World Bank Water Week, December 1995.

Briscoe, John. 1996. Water resources management in Chile: Lessons from a World Bank study tour, World Bank, Washington DC, 12 pages

Briscoe, John. 1996a. Water resources management in Mendoza, Argentina: Lessons from a World Bank study tour, World Bank, Washington DC, 8 pages.

Cheret, Ivan. 1994. Managing water: The French model, in: Valuing the Environment, World Bank, Washington DC.

Dudley, Norman. Decentralized water allocation under stochastic supply and demand: Some Australian experience. Centre for Water Policy Research, Armidale, 23 pages.

Fisher, Franklin. 1994. An economic framework for water management and negotiation. Institute for Social and Economic Policy in the Middle East, Harvard University, 10 pages.

Gazmuri, Renato and Mark Rosegrant 1996. Chilean water policy: The role of water rights, institutions and markets. Water Resources Development, Vol 12, No.1, pp 33-48.

Gibbons, Diana C. 1986. The Economic Value of Water. Resources for the Future, Washington DC, 101 pages.

Glick, Thomas F. 1969. Irrigation and Society in Medieval Valencia. Harvard University Press, Cambridge.

Goodland, Robert. 1996. The environmental sustainability challenge for the hydro industry. Hydropower and dams, 1, 37-42.

Griffin, Charles, J. Briscoe, B. Singh, R. Ramasubban and R.Bhatia. 1995. Contingent valuation and actual behavior: Predicting connections to new water systems in Kerala, India. World Bank Economic Review, 9,1,373-395.

International Conference on Water and the Environment ("the Dublin Conference"), 1992. The Dublin Statement, World Meteorological Organization, Geneva.

Lal, Padma. 1990. Conservation or conversion of mangroves in Fiji. East-West Center, Honolulu.

Maass, A and R. Anderson. 1978. And the Desert Shall Rejoice, MIT Press, Cambridge.

Mead, Elwood. 1903. Irrigation Institutions. Macmillan, New York.

Moore, Deborah and Zach Willey. 1991. Water in the American West: Institutional Evolution and Environmental Restoration in the 21st Century. University of Colorado Law Review, 62,4, 775-825.

Oxford English Dictionary. 1971. Compact Dictionary, Oxford University Press, p2558.

Postel, Sandra. 1992. Last Oasis: Facing Water Scarcity, Norton, New York.

Reissner, Marc. 1986. Cadillac Desert: The American West and its Disappearing Water. Viking, New York.

Repetto, Robert. 1986. Skimming the water: Rent-seeking and the performance of public irrigation systems. World Resources Institute, Washington DC. 46 pages.

Rogers, Peter. 1986. Water: Not as cheap as you think. Technology Review 89, 8, 31-43.

Rogers, Peter. 1992. Comprehensive water resources management: A concept paper. World Bank, Infrastructure and Urban Development Department, WPS 879, 1992.

Ruhrverband. 1992. Tasks and structure. Essen

Saliba, Bonnie Colby, and David B.Bush. 1987. Water Markets in Theory and Practice. Westview Press.

Serageldin, Ismail. 1994. Water supply, sanitation and environmental sustainability: The financing challenge. Directions in Development, World bank, Washington DC, 35 pages.

Shah, Tushaar. 1993. Groundwater Markets and Irrigation Development: Political Economy and Practical Policy, Oxford University Press, New Delhi.

Thomas, Harold A Jr. 1963. The animal farm: A mathematical model for the discussion of standards for the control of the environment. The Quarterly Journal of Economics.

Turvey, R. and J.J.Warford. 1974. Urban water and sewerage pricing. PUN 11, World Bank, Washington DC.

Wade, Robert. 1986. Corruption, delivery systems and property rights. World Development, XIV (1), 127-132.

World Bank. 1992. World Development Report 1992: Development and the Environment, Oxford University Press, New York.

World Bank. 1993. Water Resources Management. A World Bank Policy paper. Washington DC.

World Bank Water Demand Research Team. 1993. The demand for water in rural areas: determinants and policy implications. World Bank Research Observer 8(1),
47-70.

World Bank.1994. World Development Report 1994: Investing in Infrastructure, Oxford University Press, New York.

World Bank, 1994a. Unpublished report on water resources management in Andhra Pradesh, India.

World Bank, 1995. The World Bank and Irrigation, A World Bank Operations Evaluation Study, 1995

Worster, Donald. 1992. Rivers of Empire: Water, Aridity and Growth of the American West. Oxford University Press, New York.

Zachary, C. Pascal.1996. Water rights may become more liquid. Wall Street Journal, Feb 15, pages A2-4.


 Back to the top of this paper


Last updated 30th May '98